Instead
of Austen and Balzac, the professor [Piketty] ought to read "Animal
Farm" and "Darkness at Noon."
--The Wall Street Journal Any reading of Piketty’s Capital in the Twenty-First Century has to come to terms with the conditions of possibility for its popularity. Why has Thomas Piketty become a “rock star”? In part, Piketty’s text concretizes left-liberal consensus around contemporary capitalism, and does so in a way amenable to the technocratic, social-managerial orientations of left-liberalism: with data, lots of it, stretched over a long enough period to induce a kind of bleak fatalist belief in capitalism’s sempiternality. Like the political scientists about whom I last blogged, Piketty’s work in part repackages the commonly known as the expertly known. But—and here’s the other part, and one that distinguishes his work from that of those whom I critiqued—he does so in a way that validates historically common ways of knowing the economic. Every review has remarked upon the prominence of the cultural within Capital in the Twenty-First Century. The problem has been one of determining the relationship between the cultural object and the economic analysis. For Piketty’s WSJ reviewer cited above, the cultural seems to provide, maximally, a kind of overarching attunement to the phenomena discussed; minimally, a kind of shorthand for the bundling of norms and facts presented in the text. For others, Piketty’s fun with Austen, Balzac, and Don Draper are pedagogically useful, sure, but somewhat ornamental, even superfluous. The reviewer in The Nation writes
“Discussions of Balzac and Jane Austen are mildly helpful as demonstrations of the attitudes toward capital in the nineteenth century, but they offer rapidly diminishing returns and do little to substantiate Piketty’s strange contention that novelists have lost interest in the details of money, a claim plausible only to someone who has never heard of Tom Wolfe or Martin Amis. Other references—Mad Men, Django Unchained, Damages and, repeatedly, Titanic—add even less.”
Culture
as attitude, culture as exemplum—ultimately, culture as superfluous.
But
that’s not quite right. For Piketty isn’t simply staging the “attitudes” of
European bourgeoisies to capitalism in the early nineteenth century. Rather, he
is staging the adequacy of their
representations of it. (In that, he’s riding the rails laid down by a gang of
Marxist literary scholars.) Conversely, I take Piketty’s claim (which struck me
as bizarre at first, too) that novelists don’t talk about money anymore to mark
less an empirical fact than an epistemological disadequation. That is, cultural
objects might represent the economic today, but they cannot know it in a referentially meaningful
way. If Tom Wolfe is talking about money, he might as well not be. It’s
intriguing, in this regard, that the contemporary aesthetic objects that Piketty
is drawn toward tend to be historical fictions (Mad Men, Django
Unchained, Titanic), as if
art can know economic pasts but can’t get a grip on its present.
With
his literary “demonstrations,” I am suggesting, Piketty forces readers to
reckon with the constitutive break between the literary and economic
epistemologies and forms of representation. Another way of putting this: The
novel used to be able to know the economic in a referentially adequate way. It
no longer can. What each citation of Austen recalls was a harmonious time in
which literary and economic epistemologies weren’t so different, when literary
and economic genres of writing could blend together, a time before the literary
and the economic were made to part ways. (Defoe would probably be a better
example, but Austen was writing through a point of takeoff. On the general
relationship between literary and economic writing in the Anglosphere, read
this.) It’s a subdued point of the book, but it’s there: the material
inequalities associated with capitalism’s takeoff had their parallel in an
induced epistemological inequality. Literature became ornamental, literary
works mere “demonstrations” illustrative of more robust economic concepts (a la
Harriet Martineau’s gawdawful Illustrations of Political Economy [1834]), as a gaggle of political
economists reconstituted economic inquiry as an epistemologically and
generically autonomous field, a field ruled by experts. In a certain way, then,
Piketty’s account of the accumulation of inequality is equally an account—vague,
to be sure—of why it takes an economist to tell you that this is the case. Just
as capital maldistributes wealth, so too does it maldistribute knowledge. His
literary “demonstrations” put us in a position to experience the cognitive
disembedding of the economic from the phenomenologies of the everyday,
phenomenologies that can be accessed in literature and film.
Of course, questions of epistemology and genres of
representation are not Piketty’s primary concern, but he can’t not touch
upon them. For two reasons. Piketty is concerned to set off a struggle
over method in economics departments, which he sees as too mathematized, too
abstract, too ahistorical—in a phrase, too much of all the things that make it
impenetrable to lay people. At the same time, Piketty’s own handling of his
massive sets of data, his mode of interpreting and his form of representing it,
requires that his readers take a relaxed approach to statistical precision.
Precision and referential adequacy take a back seat to the omnipresent U curve. Limitations on data, as well
as decisions over how to establish and arrange variables, make all figures
figural. No matter how dense the data, economists have to play fast and loose
with figures all the time—which is why, yes, it might matter whether one is
reading Austen or Orwell.
So, if Piketty is a “rock star,” maybe it’s because
there’s something a little punky, a little DIY, a little put-together-on-the-run at work in
his text. And that’s what I want to hold on to from a book I really truly
hated. It’s been depressing to me that people are reading Piketty’s book as if
they’re learning something substantive about the world through economics when,
as I understand it, Piketty’s work makes legible the primitive accumulation of
economic knowledge, the enclosure of a proper sphere of economic knowledge that
cut into spaces of the commonly known. Indeed, the last book on economic
history to inspire an analogous, but lower-key, kind of pop frenzy—Graeber’s Debt—worked
precisely to re-embed economic thinking in the space of the social, to common
economic thinking by turning to the genre of the anecdote, the ethnography.
Alas, it was written off by a certain socialist publication—“We need more grand
histories, but 5,000 years of anecdotes is no substitute for real political
economy,” as the banner runs—which, alongside many left-lite publications, is
going (to go) gaga for Tommy P. But to posit the non-substitutability of genres
of the ordinary for those of the expert is to inscribe managerialism as a
guiding principle of our radicalism. It’s also to subordinate one’s epistemic
autonomy to experts, thereby foregoing the radical work of developing ways of
knowing in common. The enthusiasm over Piketty, in other words, is
premised on a refusal of epistemic autonomy, of the work of epistemic communization. Let me be clear: I simply
cannot imagine that the US left has learned anything useful or meaningful from
Piketty’s book, so I can only understand the book’s enthused reception in those
quarters as a ritualization of epistemic lack. Let’s call it the socialist’s
Daddy-Mommy-Me: the economist, his data, and the good little boy just so
pleased that ma and pa have validated his sense of the real.
Let’s hold on to the punky Piketty, then, the one
in the midst of an oedipal revolt against the discipline. The one who insists
that “the distribution of wealth is too important an issue to be left to
economists, sociologists, historians, and philosophers,” who insists that
“[d]emocracy will never be supplanted by a republic of experts.” The literary
appears in Capital in the Twenty-First Century as one enactment of this
epistemic democracy—a lost democracy, to be sure, one that was never really
democratic anyhow, but one that persists as a sign of alternative
epistemological ecologies. To read with the punky Piketty—and against
the feted prof who insists several times that “[i]nequality is not necessarily
bad in itself”—is to continue the work of democratizing economic knowledge. To
see in a novel, in an ethnographic anecdote, or in the performative scene of
submission conjured on payday the knowledges we need to know. And what we know,
in the form of knowledge generated in these encounters, is that economics is
ultimately defective for democracy: to democratize economic knowledge is to
destroy it.
A Marxist review of Piketty's book is at
ReplyDeletehttp://mltoday.com/professor-piketty-fights-orthodoxy-and-attacks-inequality
This comment has been removed by the author.
ReplyDeleteIt seems to me that Piketty is just a part of the endemic Euro- especially French and German tendency- to point at the extremes of American capitalism while forgetting their multi-national corporate roots and burying any real critique of globalized capitalist power. It's sort of an obnoxious plea for the coca-cola light of capitalism.I found in Germany that those who were resistant to redistributive politics at the local and international level-i.e. Greece- and also those prone to overlook the country's massive arms production- were precisely those who were most obsessed with the extremities and lawlessness of America's brand of capitalism.
ReplyDelete